New User Registration| Wednesday, January 07, 2004
Advanced Search

Capital

Industries

Profiles

Q&A

Regions

Briefings

Metrics

MARKETS

  DOW     NASD     NYSE  
DOW
 10529.03 
-9.63 
NASD
 2077.68 
+20.31 
NYSE
 6525.30 
-15.85 
S&P
 1126.33 
+2.66 
   Delayed 20 mins. 

About Forum

Red Herring Forum is a place to discuss and debate issues important to the technology business community. All opinions published here are screened. They come from people qualified to discuss the topic, and must include the name of the author and their Professional Affiliation in order to be published.


 

In defense of prediction markets

Alexander Tabarrok

In late July, word of a new Pentagon program headed by John Poindexter - allowing people to bet money on the odds of such events as political assassinations and acts of terror - caused quite a stir in the U.S. Senate. It was quickly "disestablished" by the military. The concept, however, is little understood by the public.

The concept springs from a long history of open markets - from public stocks to commodities exchanges. The insurance industry itself is a kind of market hedge against tragic events.

Symantec - Click here for more info.
We asked Alexander Tabarrok, associate professor of economics at George Mason University in Fairfax, Virginia, to explain why he thinks the idea should have been given a chance, and why similar markets for predicting the future may still play a big role in business and government.


In light of the massive failure of the U.S. intelligence agencies to avert the events of 9/11, one would think that politicians would be eager to try to develop better institutions for collecting data. Yet, when one such innovative endeavor - the Policy Analysis Market (PAM) - was recently proposed, Senators Ron Wyden (Democrat, Oregon) and Byron Dorgan (Democrat, North Dakota) labeled it a "terror market." And before the idea itself could be discussed or rationally debated, the program was terminated.

However, the concept of "information markets" or "prediction markets," has been proven successful by industry. The best known is the Iowa Political Stock Market. The Iowa market lets traders use real money to buy and sell "shares" of political candidates. A share in George W. Bush, for example, pays $1 if President Bush wins the next election and nothing otherwise. If the market price for a Bush share is 75 cents, this suggests that market participants think that President Bush has a 75 percent chance of winning the next election.

The Iowa markets have passed the market test. The Iowa market has proven to be more accurate than polls (see "Results from a Dozen Years of Election Futures Markets Research" and "Accuracy and Forecast Standard Error of Prediction Markets" for details) in nearly 14 years of predicting U.S. and foreign elections, primaries, and other political events. In tight elections, professional bond traders - who often have millions of dollars riding on post-election economic policies - monitor the Iowa markets for clues about future events.

Hewlett-Packard has used a similar market approach to help predict future hardware sales. Members of HP's sales team bought and sold shares that paid off when sales fell within a certain range. A typical security would pay out $1, if and only if, future sales were, say, between 10,000 and 15,000 units. Another might pay off if sales fell between 15,000 and 20,000 units. The market contained 10 types of securities - a range broad enough to include all the relevant possible sales outcomes.

By examining the prices of all 10 shares, HP could assign a probability to any combination of outcomes - a more nuanced analysis than that available from a questionnaire. They could determine, for example, the probability of sales falling anywhere below 10,000 units or anywhere above 25,000 units.

HP subsidized participation in the information market, so the traders could not lose money. But the traders could keep any money that they made, giving them substantial incentive to trade carefully. HP compared the implicit forecasts made by the prediction market with its own official forecasts and with actual sales figures. In 15 out of 16 trials, the mean market-based prediction was significantly closer to the actual sales figure than the official forecast. In the one remaining trial, the mean market prediction and the official forecast were equally close. Encouraged by these results, HP created its own experimental economics laboratory.

Another advantage is that these markets encourage traders to put their money where their mouths are not. The members of a company's sales team rarely has incentive to tell their bosses that next quarter's sales are going to be lower than expected.

Siemens used a similar internal prediction market to help forecast when a project would be completed. The market correctly predicted a longer delay than the official forecast, revealing a comparable reluctance on the part of Siemens's staff to "tell it like it is." Prediction markets can help to overcome the "yes-man" phenomenon, which makes it difficult for information to rise from the field to the decision makers.

The Hollywood Stock Exchange (HSX) is also proving that the innovative use of markets can be profitable. The Hollywood Exchange lets traders buy and sell shares and options in movies, music, and Oscar contenders. Trading on the Hollywood exchange is conducted in make-believe "Hollywood Dollars," but the goal of HSX - which is owned by a subsidiary of the trading firm Cantor Fitzgerald - is profit. Some 800,000 people trading on HSX for fun have proven to be reliable indicators of future film profits, and HSX is now selling its data to Hollywood studios eager to improve their predictions about future blockbusters.

In Entrepreneurial Economics: Bright Ideas from the Dismal Science (Oxford University Press, 2002), economist Robin Hanson of George Mason University explains how information markets could be used to help answer public policy questions. A market might be formed, for example, to predict the crime rate if a piece of gun-control legislation passed or failed. (The PAM market was going to forecast events such as total yearly casualties from terrorism if, for example, the U.S. invaded Syria or withdrew its troops from Saudi Arabia.) Such political information markets could replace the less accurate information-gathering mechanisms that we use to make political decisions today. Marketocracy could replace democracy.

Markets, of course, are not perfect. Instead of predicting future revenues, the market prices of many dot.com stocks seemed to reflect belief in the sucker-born-every-minute principle. Occasionally, markets can even be cornered and turned to the advantage of particularly powerful investors. (One concern about PAM was that terrorists could use it to make money off their acts, although there are far better - and more anonymous - ways to do that, such as shorting airline stocks before a hijacking or shorting beef prices before introducing mad cow disease.) Yet, one of the most intriguing aspects of the research being done in economics laboratories at HP, IBM, and universities around the world is the potential to discover rules and procedures that make markets less susceptible to irrational exuberance and cornering. Careful design of prediction markets could enhance their forecasting ability.

Business people know that markets are important institutions of a well-run society. But until recently, few thought of them as important tools for running their businesses. The uncanny ability of markets to usefully aggregate and quantify large amounts of dispersed information, however, indicates that such markets should be taken more seriously as tools to predict everything from quarterly sales to consumer preferences.

And if information markets can help business, why not the CIA, FBI and other security risk analysts as well? Despite being attacked by sound-biting senators, the evidence strongly suggests that this innovative approach to intelligence gathering and processing could have improved the capability of the intelligence services before 9/11. Although abandoned by government, we may yet see private firms using the information processing power of prediction markets to help us decide contentious political questions and forecast geopolitical events, including those impacting terrorism.

Alexander Tabarrok is research director for The Independent Institute, associate professor of economics at George Mason University, and editor of Entrepreneurial Economics: Bright Ideas from the Dismal Science.

What's Your Opinion

Click here to post your comments



   
Register free
 
Member Sign-in
 
email:
password:
 
  Lost Password?

Remember me on this computer

NetApp: Enterprise Storage Solutions


Label